
Can Price Segmentation Avoid A Music Streaming Malthusian Trap?
The music streaming industry is at a breaking point, with artists facing dwindling payouts in an expanding market. Can price segmentation be the solution to avoid the music streaming Malthusian trap and restore fairness for creators?
Definition: The Malthusian Trap is the theory that population growth outpaces resource growth, leading to famine, war, and poverty
Can Price Segmentation Avoid A Music Streaming Malthusian Trap?
Op-ed from Chris Castle via Music Tech Solutions

When you see artists and songwriters getting starved out of the music business while at the same time fighting over scraps from streaming, that’s unusual. When you see more and more labels caring almost as much about acquiring ever more catalogs rather than helping artists in developing long-term careers, that’s unusual. Why is this becoming the norm? Could it be we are in a “Malthusian trap”?
Price segmentation in streaming music could be an effective way to avoid the economic concept of the “Malthusian trap.” Simply put, the Malthusian trap occurs when demand for resources outpaces available resources. This is most likely to happen when buyers with cash exploit sellers who want it by using price fixing and market allocation. Like the big pool method of manipulating wholesale prices.
Adopting a more sophisticated approach required by segmentation could allow the business to move away from the “big pool” program of price controls that has been adopted by every streaming service for both songs and sound recordings. It’s easy to see why this method of price fixing is attractive–it’s just killing the artists and songwriters stuck in the Malthusian trap.
The Malthusian Trap and Faux Democratization of the Denominator
The “Malthusian Trap” occurs in streaming when wholesale prices determined by the “big pool” method of price caps is overtaken by the services’ open invitation for the supposed “democratization of the denominator.” This faux “democratization” uses artists as human shields to put control of wholesale pricing squarely in the hands of streaming services due to wholesale price controls on both the sound recording and song payouts.
When the growth of a service’s sound recording offering outpaces available revenues, the “big pool” method effectively transfers control over wholesale prices from rights holders to services and causes diminishing returns for both labels and publishers. Regardless of the terms of any one artist’s record deal or the convoluted compulsory mechanical royalty for songwriters, these diminishing returns will hit artists, producers and songwriters because returns are diminished to the labels and publishers, particularly on a per-artist basis. Particular deals may make the decline even more pronounced, but the race to the bottom is baked into the model.
By introducing a more dynamic and differentiated pricing model, rights holders could regain control over their own wholesale prices, streaming services might better align revenue payouts with actual usage and consumer preferences, and we could all potentially avoid the scenario where a fixed revenue pool gets stretched too thin across an ever-expanding catalog.
It must also be said that because performance on Spotify is closely tied–so to speak–to other commerce such as talent buyers for live shows that constantly check how a new artist has performed on Spotify before giving them a show date, a relatively simple economic decision becomes complex. A demonetized artist may be economically indifferent to continuing to support Spotify by driving fans to the platform, but removing themselves from Spotify may hurt them in booking live shows. So the big pool needs to get blown up for yet another valid, if not actionable, reason.
Blowing Up the Compulsory
On the songwriter side, there is a sense that what we really need to do is blow up the compulsory license particularly given the reaming songwriters are taking from Spotify’s exploitation of the “bundle” loophole that has foolishly been in the Copyright Royalty Board’s regulations for many, many years. But even so, I suggest that the path dependence of 100-plus years of reliance by a wide variety of music users on the U.S. compulsory mechanical license is unlikely to get “blown up” and abandoned by lawmakers. But what may get “blown up” is the hated “big pool” royalty payable under that compulsory. It may turn out that it’s the big pool that is the culprit, not the compulsory license. (And by the way–be careful what you wish for with all this “blowing up” of the compulsory. You may really not want who comes next.)
Why are we still suffering under this ancient regime? Unfortunately, when the handful of people who forced through Title I of the Music Modernization Act got done with it in 2018, they made bad choices. For example, they had a golden opportunity to do something simple like shorten the rate period from five years to a realistic duration that more closely matches the term of direct license agreements. It’s simply bizarre to use a five year term during a contemporary era marked by relatively high inflation when rates during the 1988-2004 period were adjusted every two years.
They also had a chance to choose between perpetuating the DMV-style model of licensing administration in favor of creating an Apple Store-style model and they went for “more DMV please” like carp on bait. And here we are, more screwed than ever. Gee thanks, thought leaders!
Understanding the Malthusian Trap in Streaming
In the current “big pool” model, royalties are divided among artists based on the proportion of streams their music receives relative to the total number of streams on the platform. Songwriters are paid in a similar version of the “big pool.” This system leads to diminishing payouts as the catalog expands and the user base grows, since:
– The total revenue pool remains relatively static due to slowing streaming growth and frozen subscription prices, while the denominator (the total number of streams) grows larger.
– The more content added to the platform, the less valuable each individual stream becomes (regardless of particular artist deals).
– Artists or songwriters with fewer streams get demonetized by Spotify or are paid but fall outside the mainstream struggle to receive meaningful payouts.
The “Malthusian trap,” in this context means there is an imbalanced relationship between increasing content and relatively static revenue pools. That imbalance results in declining payouts over time for artists and songwriters. This especially true for those creators whose total streams (the numerator in the ratio) are relatively constant or declining due to falling off in fan engagement for whatever reason (including bands that break up or artists who pass away).
In other words, the big pool’s fixed cap on aggregated streaming prices creates its own scarcity despite the infinite shelf space of a streaming service. (See Chris Anderson’s rather tarnished “long tail” theory that still reigns supreme at streaming services which demonstrated once again there is no free lunch.)
“Malthusian” refers to the sometimes controversial ideas of Thomas Robert Malthus (1766–1834) the British economist, scholar, and demographer, best known for his theories on population growth and its relationship to resources, particularly food. His most influential work is “An Essay on the Principle of Population” (1798), where he argued that populations tend to grow exponentially, while food production grows at a much slower, linear rate. This mismatch, according to Malthus, would eventually lead to overpopulation and resource scarcity, resulting in widespread poverty, famine, and social instability. Malthus called this the “surplus population” or what the AI accelerationists call “useless eaters.” Surplus population leads to famine just like streaming leads to Discovery Mode and demonetization. Mr. Malthus has a fairly gloomy view of the world, so no Spotify stock options for him. He wouldn’t have his pompoms out as a streaming cheerleader our Thomas, but his ideas are very relevant to the streaming analysis.

Key Concepts of Malthusian Theory: Also see Malthus critic Charles Dickens (“may I have some more”), England’s response to the Irish potato famine and Gangs of New York.
Exponential Population Growth: Malthus believed that if left unchecked, populations grow exponentially (doubling every 25 years), which would outpace the resources needed to sustain them. Comparatively, the total number of tracks on Spotify has doubled approximately every four years. (This is like Sergei’s Corollary to Moore’s Law–royalties decline 50% with every two year increase in computing power.)
Limited Food Supply: Malthus argued that food production could only grow at an arithmetic (linear) rate because of the finite land, labor, and capital available to produce it. Over time, the availability of food per capita would diminish just like the per-stream rate on streaming platforms–that’s why Spotify continues to deny a per-stream rate even exists (ludicrous propaganda). That is, populations tend to increase geometrically (2, 4, 8, 16 …), whereas food reserves grow arithmetically (2, 3, 4, 5 …). I’d say this is like a vast number of under performing recordings lead to competition for the artificially capped revenue under “big pool” and the relatively frozen subscription prices. This helps to explain Daniel Ek’s–very Malthusian–comment that artists need to work harder to keep up which was straight out of Oliver Twist.
The Malthusian Trap: The theory suggests that any improvements in living standards (through better agriculture, technology, or economic progress) would eventually lead to population growth, which would, in turn, bring the standard of living back down to subsistence levels. Essentially, population pressure would cause periodic famines, diseases, or wars–you know, demonetization–that would control population size and maintain balance with available resources. The trap helps to explain why we need to blow up the big pool model and its fixed wholesale prices.
Preventive and Positive Checks: Malthus identified two types of checks on population growth:
Preventive checks: These are voluntary actions people can take to limit population growth, such as delayed marriage and celibacy. In the streaming analogy, this would occur if Spotify were to limit the number of royalty bearing tracks (like demonetizing under 1,000 streams).
Positive checks: These occur when the population exceeds the capacity for sustenance, leading to famine, disease, and mortality, which ultimately reduce the population. In the streaming analogy, this occurs when artists or songwriters quit the music business or abandon streaming platforms. Given the close ties between traction on Spotify and validation for talent buyers, for example, it is unlikely that a working artist could abandon the platform entirely no matter how much it costs them to stay on Spotify–although there are limits.
Can Price Segmentation Address the Malthusian Trap in Streaming?
Price segmentation allows streaming platforms to differentiate pricing based on different user segments, content types, or usage behaviors, which can provide several key benefits to avoid the Malthusian trap. We’ll see if the thought leaders have some other suggestions–that I cynically (I admit) think are most likely to be continuing to put bandaids on the status quo.